Three canonical models of Oligopoly
Antoine Augustin Cournot
1801-1877
1838 Researches on the Mathematical Principles of the Theory of Wealth
First writer to:
Sadly, no influence in his lifetime, but enormous consequence on neoclassical economics
Cournot, Antoine Augustin, 1838, Researches on the Mathematical Principles of the Theory of Wealth
Antoine Augustin Cournot
1801-1877
Antoine Augustin Cournot
1801-1877
“Let us now imagine two proprietors and two springs of which qualities are identical and which on account of their similar positions supply the same market in competition.”
“In this case the price is necessarily the same for each proprietor.”
“If p is the price, D=F(p) the total sales, D1 the sales from the spring (1), and D2 the sales from the spring (2), then D1+D2=D.”
Antoine Augustin Cournot
1801-1877
“If, to begin with, we neglect the cost of production, the respective incomes of the proprietors will be pD1 and pD2 and...each of them independently will seek to make this income as large as possible.”
“[But] [p]roprietor (1) can have no direct influence on the determination of D2.”
“All that he can do when D2 has been determined by proprietor (2) is to choose for D1 the value which is best for him. This he will be able to accomplish by properly adjusting his price...except as proprietor (2), who seeing himself forced to accept his price and this value of D2, may adopt a new value for D2 more favorable ot his interests than the preceding one.”
Antoine Augustin Cournot
1801-1877
We use modern game theory and Nash equilibrium to make Cournot’s model a static game (for now)
“Cournot competition”: two (or more) firms compete on quantity to sell the same good
Firms set their quantities simultaneously
Firms' joint output determines the market price faced by all firms
Suppose two firms (1 and 2), each have an identical constant cost MC(q)=AC(q)=c
Firm 1 and Firm 2 simultaneously set quantities, q1 and q2
Total market demand is given by
P=a−bQQ=q1+q2
π1=q1(P−c)π1=q1(a−b(q1+q2)−c)
And, symmetrically same for firm 2
Note each firm's profits depend (in part) on the output of the other firm!
Consider the demand each firm faces to be a residual demand
e.g. for firm 1, it's (residual) demand is:
Consider the demand each firm faces to be a residual demand
e.g. for firm 1, it's (residual) demand is:
p=a−b(q1+q2)p=(a−bq2)⏟intercept−b⏟slopeq1
Consider the demand each firm faces to be a residual demand
e.g. for firm 1, it's (residual) demand is:
p=a−b(q1+q2)p=(a−bq2)⏟intercept−b⏟slopeq1
Consider the demand each firm faces to be a residual demand
e.g. for firm 1, it's (residual) demand is:
p=a−b(q1+q2)p=(a−bq2)⏟intercept−b⏟slopeq1
Firm 2 will produce some amount, q2.
Firm 1 takes this as given, to find its own residual demand
Firm 2 will produce some amount, q2.
Firm 1 will take this as a given, a constant
Firm 1's choice variable is q1, given q2
Example: Assume Coke (c) and Pepsi (p) are the only two cola producers, each with a constant MC=AC=$0.50. The market (inverse) demand curve is given by: P=5−0.05QQ=qc+qp
Example: Assume Coke (c) and Pepsi (p) are the only two cola producers, each with a constant MC=AC=$0.50. The market (inverse) demand curve is given by: P=5−0.05QQ=qc+qp
P=5−0.05Q
Example: Assume Coke (c) and Pepsi (p) are the only two cola producers, each with a constant MC=AC=$0.50. The market (inverse) demand curve is given by: P=5−0.05QQ=qc+qp
P=5−0.05Q
P=5−0.05qc−0.05qp
P=5−0.05qc−0.05qp
P=5−0.05qc−0.05qp
P=5−0.05qp⏟intercept−0.05⏟slopeqc
Firms maximize profit (as always), by setting q∗:MR(q)=MC(q)
Solve for Coke’s MR(q) first:
P=5−0.05qp⏟intercept−0.05⏟slopeqc
Firms maximize profit (as always), by setting q∗:MR(q)=MC(q)
Solve for Coke’s MR(q) first:
MRc=5−0.05qp−0.10qc
Solve for q∗ for each firm (where MR(q)=MC(q)), we derive each firm's reaction function or best response function to the other firm's output
Symmetric marginal costs and marginal revenues
Solve for q∗ for each firm (where MR(q)=MC(q)), we derive each firm's reaction function or best response function to the other firm's output
Symmetric marginal costs and marginal revenues
q∗c=45−0.5qpq∗p=45−0.5qc
We can graph Coke's reaction curve to Pepsi's output
We can graph Coke's reaction curve to Pepsi's output
We can graph Coke's reaction curve to Pepsi's output
We can graph Pepsi's reaction curve to Coke's output
We can graph Pepsi's reaction curve to Coke's output
We can graph Pepsi's reaction curve to Coke's output
Combine both curves on the same graph
Cournot-Nash Equilibrium: (30,30)
Both are playing mutual best response to one another
q∗c=30−0.5qpq∗p=30−0.5qc
q∗c=30−0.5qpq∗p=30−0.5qc
P=5−0.05qc−0.05qp
P=5−0.05(30+30)P=$2.00
P=5−0.05(30+30)P=$2.00
P=5−0.05(30+30)P=$2.00
πc=qc(P−c)πc=30(2.00−0.50)πc=45
MR=MC5−0.1Q=0.5045=Q∗
MR=MC5−0.1Q=0.5045=Q∗
P=5−0.05(45)P=$2.75
MR=MC5−0.1Q=0.5045=Q∗
P=5−0.05(45)P=$2.75
Π=45($2.75−$0.50)=$101.25
with $50.625 going to each firm
Cournot Competition: each firm produces 30 and earns $45.00
Collusion/Monopoly: each firm produces 22.5 and earns $50.63
Cournot Competition: each firm produces 30 and earns $45.00
Collusion/Monopoly: each firm produces 22.5 and earns $50.63
But is collusion a Nash equilibrium?
Read either firm's reaction curve at the collusive outcome
Suppose Coke knows Pepsi is producing 22.5 (as per the cartel agreement)
Coke's best response to Pepsi's 22.5 is to produce 33.75
πc=qc(P−c)πc=33.75(2.1875−0.50)πc=$56.95
πc=qc(P−c)πc=33.75(2.1875−0.50)πc=$56.95
πp=qp(P−c)πp=22.5(2.1875−0.50)πp=$37.97
Example: Suppose Firm 1 and Firm 2 have a constant MC=AC=8. The market (inverse) demand curve is given by:
P=200−2QQ=q1+q2
Find the Cournot-Nash equilibrium output and profit for each firm.
Find the output and profit for each firm if the two were to collude.
Suppose Coke's marginal cost decreases (such that MCc<MCp)
Profit maximization requires MCc=MRc, so it will produce more (at q2c)
Or equivalently, suppose Coke's marginal revenue increases (such that MRc>MRp)
Profit maximization requires MCc=MRc, so it will produce more (at q2c)
In either case, Coke becomes more efficient than Pepsi (lower cost/higher revenues)
Coke will produce more output
Pepsi will produce less output as a response
Overall industry output increases; price decreases
Profits to Coke increase; profits to Pepsi decrease
If a firm has lower costs/higher revenues than others, it earns greater profit
Competing firms will want to:
So far we've assumed the number of firms exogenously: two.
But as in any market, profits will attract entry
Let's make the number of firms endogenous, determined by the market conditions
Symmetrically, in equilibrium, each firm will be selling 1N=si of industry output
e.g. with 5 firms, each sells 15 of Q, market share of 20% each
Each firm earns profits πi(N)
MRi=[a−bN∑j≠iqj]⏟intercept−2bqi
a−bN∑j≠iqj−2bqi=c
a−bN∑j≠iqj−2bqi=c
a−bN∑j≠iqj−2bqi=c
a−b(N−1)q∗−2bq∗=c
a−b(N−1)q∗−2bq∗=c
q∗=a−c(N+1)b
a−b(N−1)q∗−2bq∗=c
q∗=a−c(N+1)b
Q∗=N(a−c)(N+1)b
a−b(N−1)q∗−2bq∗=c
q∗=a−c(N+1)b
Q∗=N(a−c)(N+1)b
p∗=A+NcN+1
a−b(N−1)q∗−2bq∗=c
q∗=a−c(N+1)b
Q∗=N(a−c)(N+1)b
p∗=A+NcN+1
πi=(a−cN+1)2(1b)
See pp.243-244 of the textbook for algebraic derivations.
a−b(N−1)q∗−2bq∗=c
q∗=a−c(N+1)b
Q∗=N(a−c)(N+1)b
p∗=A+NcN+1
πi=(a−cN+1)2(1b)
See pp.243-244 of the textbook for algebraic derivations.
p−MCp=1εN
So far we've assumed no formal barriers to entry, so firms are free to enter and exit
In Cournot equilibrium, how many firms will there be (i.e. what is N)?
Constant returns to scale leads to a problem!
Regardless of number of firms N, p∗>AC always!
Nothing limits the entry of firms! (Not a satisfactory theory)
Consider instead a case with economies of scale for each firm i Ci(qi)=cqi+f
Barrier to entry from cost-disadvantage to small-scale entry
Equilibrium where p=AC(q⋆)
Profits with N firms are again πi=(a−cN+1)2(1b)
Fixed costs don't change any incentives on the margin to produce
Fixed costs only affect the incentive to enter
For our Coke & Pepsi example, suppose producing soda comes with a $10.00 fixed cost. How many firms would be in the industry in a free-entry equilibrium?
For our Coke & Pepsi example, suppose producing soda comes with a $10.00 fixed cost. How many firms would be in the industry in a free-entry equilibrium?
π=f(a−cN+1)2(1b)=f(5−0.5N+1)210.05=10.00N∗=5.36
5 firms; a sixth firm could not profitably enter
(If N is not a whole number, the last whole number is the answer)
In general,
N∗=a−c√bf−1
N | qi | Q | AC(qi) | p | πi |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
1 | 45.00 | 45.00 | $0.72 | $2.75 | $91.25 |
2 | 30.00 | 60.00 | $0.83 | $2.00 | $35.00 |
3 | 22.50 | 67.50 | $0.94 | $1.625 | $15.31 |
4 | 18.00 | 72.00 | $1.06 | $1.40 | $6.20 |
5 | 15.00 | 75.00 | $1.17 | $1.25 | $1.25 |
6 | 12.86 | 77.14 | $1.28 | $1.14 | -$1.73 |
For our Coke & Pepsi example, suppose producing soda comes with a $75.00 fixed cost. How many firms would be in the industry in a free-entry equilibrium?
For our Coke & Pepsi example, suppose producing soda comes with a $75.00 fixed cost. How many firms would be in the industry in a free-entry equilibrium?
π=f(a−cN+1)2(1b)=f(5−0.5N+1)210.05=75.00N∗=1.32
N | qi | Q | AC(qi) | p | πi |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
1 | 45.00 | 45.00 | $2.06 | $2.75 | $31.25 |
2 | 30.00 | 60.00 | $2.83 | $2.00 | -$25.00 |
With high enough fixed costs, even a single firm (monopolist) would not enter!
Might make sense for government to subsidize a monopolist to break even
P−MCP⏟Lerner index=siε
P−MCP⏟Lerner index=siε
P−MCP=siε
N∑i=1si(P−MCP)=N∑i=1sisiε
N∑i=1si(P−MCP)=HHIε
HHI = Herfindahl-Hirschmann Index (sum of squared market shares); a famous measure of industry concentration (we'll explore later)†
The larger the HHI (holding ε constant), the greater the average weighted markup/industry-wide Lerner index (lefthand side)
Implication: if Cournot model is accurate, measuring the HHI and ε provide good empirical evidence about firm conduct
† In the U.S., HHI is often measured using market shares as percentages, making HHI between 0 and 10,000.
Three canonical models of Oligopoly
Keyboard shortcuts
↑, ←, Pg Up, k | Go to previous slide |
↓, →, Pg Dn, Space, j | Go to next slide |
Home | Go to first slide |
End | Go to last slide |
Number + Return | Go to specific slide |
b / m / f | Toggle blackout / mirrored / fullscreen mode |
c | Clone slideshow |
p | Toggle presenter mode |
t | Restart the presentation timer |
?, h | Toggle this help |
o | Tile View: Overview of Slides |
Esc | Back to slideshow |
Three canonical models of Oligopoly
Antoine Augustin Cournot
1801-1877
1838 Researches on the Mathematical Principles of the Theory of Wealth
First writer to:
Sadly, no influence in his lifetime, but enormous consequence on neoclassical economics
Cournot, Antoine Augustin, 1838, Researches on the Mathematical Principles of the Theory of Wealth
Antoine Augustin Cournot
1801-1877
Antoine Augustin Cournot
1801-1877
“Let us now imagine two proprietors and two springs of which qualities are identical and which on account of their similar positions supply the same market in competition.”
“In this case the price is necessarily the same for each proprietor.”
“If p is the price, D=F(p) the total sales, D1 the sales from the spring (1), and D2 the sales from the spring (2), then D1+D2=D.”
Antoine Augustin Cournot
1801-1877
“If, to begin with, we neglect the cost of production, the respective incomes of the proprietors will be pD1 and pD2 and...each of them independently will seek to make this income as large as possible.”
“[But] [p]roprietor (1) can have no direct influence on the determination of D2.”
“All that he can do when D2 has been determined by proprietor (2) is to choose for D1 the value which is best for him. This he will be able to accomplish by properly adjusting his price...except as proprietor (2), who seeing himself forced to accept his price and this value of D2, may adopt a new value for D2 more favorable ot his interests than the preceding one.”
Antoine Augustin Cournot
1801-1877
We use modern game theory and Nash equilibrium to make Cournot’s model a static game (for now)
“Cournot competition”: two (or more) firms compete on quantity to sell the same good
Firms set their quantities simultaneously
Firms' joint output determines the market price faced by all firms
Suppose two firms (1 and 2), each have an identical constant cost MC(q)=AC(q)=c
Firm 1 and Firm 2 simultaneously set quantities, q1 and q2
Total market demand is given by
P=a−bQQ=q1+q2
π1=q1(P−c)π1=q1(a−b(q1+q2)−c)
And, symmetrically same for firm 2
Note each firm's profits depend (in part) on the output of the other firm!
Consider the demand each firm faces to be a residual demand
e.g. for firm 1, it's (residual) demand is:
Consider the demand each firm faces to be a residual demand
e.g. for firm 1, it's (residual) demand is:
p=a−b(q1+q2)p=(a−bq2)⏟intercept−b⏟slopeq1
Consider the demand each firm faces to be a residual demand
e.g. for firm 1, it's (residual) demand is:
p=a−b(q1+q2)p=(a−bq2)⏟intercept−b⏟slopeq1
Consider the demand each firm faces to be a residual demand
e.g. for firm 1, it's (residual) demand is:
p=a−b(q1+q2)p=(a−bq2)⏟intercept−b⏟slopeq1
Firm 2 will produce some amount, q2.
Firm 1 takes this as given, to find its own residual demand
Firm 2 will produce some amount, q2.
Firm 1 will take this as a given, a constant
Firm 1's choice variable is q1, given q2
Example: Assume Coke (c) and Pepsi (p) are the only two cola producers, each with a constant MC=AC=$0.50. The market (inverse) demand curve is given by: P=5−0.05QQ=qc+qp
Example: Assume Coke (c) and Pepsi (p) are the only two cola producers, each with a constant MC=AC=$0.50. The market (inverse) demand curve is given by: P=5−0.05QQ=qc+qp
P=5−0.05Q
Example: Assume Coke (c) and Pepsi (p) are the only two cola producers, each with a constant MC=AC=$0.50. The market (inverse) demand curve is given by: P=5−0.05QQ=qc+qp
P=5−0.05Q
P=5−0.05qc−0.05qp
P=5−0.05qc−0.05qp
P=5−0.05qc−0.05qp
P=5−0.05qp⏟intercept−0.05⏟slopeqc
Firms maximize profit (as always), by setting q∗:MR(q)=MC(q)
Solve for Coke’s MR(q) first:
P=5−0.05qp⏟intercept−0.05⏟slopeqc
Firms maximize profit (as always), by setting q∗:MR(q)=MC(q)
Solve for Coke’s MR(q) first:
MRc=5−0.05qp−0.10qc
Solve for q∗ for each firm (where MR(q)=MC(q)), we derive each firm's reaction function or best response function to the other firm's output
Symmetric marginal costs and marginal revenues
Solve for q∗ for each firm (where MR(q)=MC(q)), we derive each firm's reaction function or best response function to the other firm's output
Symmetric marginal costs and marginal revenues
q∗c=45−0.5qpq∗p=45−0.5qc
We can graph Coke's reaction curve to Pepsi's output
We can graph Coke's reaction curve to Pepsi's output
We can graph Coke's reaction curve to Pepsi's output
We can graph Pepsi's reaction curve to Coke's output
We can graph Pepsi's reaction curve to Coke's output
We can graph Pepsi's reaction curve to Coke's output
Combine both curves on the same graph
Cournot-Nash Equilibrium: (30,30)
Both are playing mutual best response to one another
q∗c=30−0.5qpq∗p=30−0.5qc
q∗c=30−0.5qpq∗p=30−0.5qc
P=5−0.05qc−0.05qp
P=5−0.05(30+30)P=$2.00
P=5−0.05(30+30)P=$2.00
P=5−0.05(30+30)P=$2.00
πc=qc(P−c)πc=30(2.00−0.50)πc=45
MR=MC5−0.1Q=0.5045=Q∗
MR=MC5−0.1Q=0.5045=Q∗
P=5−0.05(45)P=$2.75
MR=MC5−0.1Q=0.5045=Q∗
P=5−0.05(45)P=$2.75
Π=45($2.75−$0.50)=$101.25
with $50.625 going to each firm
Cournot Competition: each firm produces 30 and earns $45.00
Collusion/Monopoly: each firm produces 22.5 and earns $50.63
Cournot Competition: each firm produces 30 and earns $45.00
Collusion/Monopoly: each firm produces 22.5 and earns $50.63
But is collusion a Nash equilibrium?
Read either firm's reaction curve at the collusive outcome
Suppose Coke knows Pepsi is producing 22.5 (as per the cartel agreement)
Coke's best response to Pepsi's 22.5 is to produce 33.75
πc=qc(P−c)πc=33.75(2.1875−0.50)πc=$56.95
πc=qc(P−c)πc=33.75(2.1875−0.50)πc=$56.95
πp=qp(P−c)πp=22.5(2.1875−0.50)πp=$37.97
Example: Suppose Firm 1 and Firm 2 have a constant MC=AC=8. The market (inverse) demand curve is given by:
P=200−2QQ=q1+q2
Find the Cournot-Nash equilibrium output and profit for each firm.
Find the output and profit for each firm if the two were to collude.
Suppose Coke's marginal cost decreases (such that MCc<MCp)
Profit maximization requires MCc=MRc, so it will produce more (at q2c)
Or equivalently, suppose Coke's marginal revenue increases (such that MRc>MRp)
Profit maximization requires MCc=MRc, so it will produce more (at q2c)
In either case, Coke becomes more efficient than Pepsi (lower cost/higher revenues)
Coke will produce more output
Pepsi will produce less output as a response
Overall industry output increases; price decreases
Profits to Coke increase; profits to Pepsi decrease
If a firm has lower costs/higher revenues than others, it earns greater profit
Competing firms will want to:
So far we've assumed the number of firms exogenously: two.
But as in any market, profits will attract entry
Let's make the number of firms endogenous, determined by the market conditions
Symmetrically, in equilibrium, each firm will be selling 1N=si of industry output
e.g. with 5 firms, each sells 15 of Q, market share of 20% each
Each firm earns profits πi(N)
MRi=[a−bN∑j≠iqj]⏟intercept−2bqi
a−bN∑j≠iqj−2bqi=c
a−bN∑j≠iqj−2bqi=c
a−bN∑j≠iqj−2bqi=c
a−b(N−1)q∗−2bq∗=c
a−b(N−1)q∗−2bq∗=c
q∗=a−c(N+1)b
a−b(N−1)q∗−2bq∗=c
q∗=a−c(N+1)b
Q∗=N(a−c)(N+1)b
a−b(N−1)q∗−2bq∗=c
q∗=a−c(N+1)b
Q∗=N(a−c)(N+1)b
p∗=A+NcN+1
a−b(N−1)q∗−2bq∗=c
q∗=a−c(N+1)b
Q∗=N(a−c)(N+1)b
p∗=A+NcN+1
πi=(a−cN+1)2(1b)
See pp.243-244 of the textbook for algebraic derivations.
a−b(N−1)q∗−2bq∗=c
q∗=a−c(N+1)b
Q∗=N(a−c)(N+1)b
p∗=A+NcN+1
πi=(a−cN+1)2(1b)
See pp.243-244 of the textbook for algebraic derivations.
p−MCp=1εN
So far we've assumed no formal barriers to entry, so firms are free to enter and exit
In Cournot equilibrium, how many firms will there be (i.e. what is N)?
Constant returns to scale leads to a problem!
Regardless of number of firms N, p∗>AC always!
Nothing limits the entry of firms! (Not a satisfactory theory)
Consider instead a case with economies of scale for each firm i Ci(qi)=cqi+f
Barrier to entry from cost-disadvantage to small-scale entry
Equilibrium where p=AC(q⋆)
Profits with N firms are again πi=(a−cN+1)2(1b)
Fixed costs don't change any incentives on the margin to produce
Fixed costs only affect the incentive to enter
For our Coke & Pepsi example, suppose producing soda comes with a $10.00 fixed cost. How many firms would be in the industry in a free-entry equilibrium?
For our Coke & Pepsi example, suppose producing soda comes with a $10.00 fixed cost. How many firms would be in the industry in a free-entry equilibrium?
π=f(a−cN+1)2(1b)=f(5−0.5N+1)210.05=10.00N∗=5.36
5 firms; a sixth firm could not profitably enter
(If N is not a whole number, the last whole number is the answer)
In general,
N∗=a−c√bf−1
N | qi | Q | AC(qi) | p | πi |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
1 | 45.00 | 45.00 | $0.72 | $2.75 | $91.25 |
2 | 30.00 | 60.00 | $0.83 | $2.00 | $35.00 |
3 | 22.50 | 67.50 | $0.94 | $1.625 | $15.31 |
4 | 18.00 | 72.00 | $1.06 | $1.40 | $6.20 |
5 | 15.00 | 75.00 | $1.17 | $1.25 | $1.25 |
6 | 12.86 | 77.14 | $1.28 | $1.14 | -$1.73 |
For our Coke & Pepsi example, suppose producing soda comes with a $75.00 fixed cost. How many firms would be in the industry in a free-entry equilibrium?
For our Coke & Pepsi example, suppose producing soda comes with a $75.00 fixed cost. How many firms would be in the industry in a free-entry equilibrium?
π=f(a−cN+1)2(1b)=f(5−0.5N+1)210.05=75.00N∗=1.32
N | qi | Q | AC(qi) | p | πi |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
1 | 45.00 | 45.00 | $2.06 | $2.75 | $31.25 |
2 | 30.00 | 60.00 | $2.83 | $2.00 | -$25.00 |
With high enough fixed costs, even a single firm (monopolist) would not enter!
Might make sense for government to subsidize a monopolist to break even
P−MCP⏟Lerner index=siε
P−MCP⏟Lerner index=siε
P−MCP=siε
N∑i=1si(P−MCP)=N∑i=1sisiε
N∑i=1si(P−MCP)=HHIε
HHI = Herfindahl-Hirschmann Index (sum of squared market shares); a famous measure of industry concentration (we'll explore later)†
The larger the HHI (holding ε constant), the greater the average weighted markup/industry-wide Lerner index (lefthand side)
Implication: if Cournot model is accurate, measuring the HHI and ε provide good empirical evidence about firm conduct
† In the U.S., HHI is often measured using market shares as percentages, making HHI between 0 and 10,000.