Ronald H. Coase
(1910-2013)
Economics Nobel 1991
John R. Commons
1862-1945
“[T]he ultimate unit of activity ... must contain in itself the three principles of conflict, mutuality, and order. This unit is a transaction,” (p.4).
Olvier E Williamson
1932-
Economics Nobel 2009
“As the term suggests, transaction cost economics adopts a microanalytic approach to the study of economic organization. The focus is on transactions and the economizing efforts that attend the organization thereof...With a well-working interface, as with a well-working machine, these transfers occur smoothly. In mechanical systems we look for frictions: Do the gears mesh, are the parts lubricated, is there needless slippage or other loss of energy?” (p.1).
Olvier E Williamson
1932-
Economics Nobel 2009
“The economic counterpart of friction is transaction cost: Do the parties to the exchange operate harmoniously, or are there frequent misunderstandings and conflicts that lead to delays, breakdowns, and other malfunctions? Transaction cost analysis supplants the usual preoccupation with technology and steady-state production (or distribution) expenses with an examination of the comparative costs of planning, adapting, and monitoring task completion under alternative governance structures.“ (pp.1-2).
Olvier E Williamson
1932-
Economics Nobel 2009
“Rather than characterize the firm as a production function, transaction cost economics maintains that the firm is (for many purposes at least) more usefully regarded as a governance structure.” (p.13)
“Contrary to earlier conceptions–where the economic institutions of capitalism are explained by reference to class interests, technology, and/or monopoly power–the transactions cost approach maintains that these institutions have the main purpose and effect of economizing on transaction costs,” (p.1).
Olvier E Williamson
1932-
Economics Nobel 2009
“Governance...is the means by which to infuse order, thereby to mitigate conflict and realize mutual gain...Furthermore, the transaction is made the basic unit of analysis,” (p.2).
Olvier E Williamson
1932-
Economics Nobel 2009
A contract between two parties constitutes a “fundamental transformation” from ex ante competitive market to an ex post bilateral monopoly
Creates the possibility of post-contractual opportunism by the parties
This bilateral dependency creates “quasi rents” from cooperation that might be appropriated by a party
Need to contract ex ante to protect ex post possibility of someone threatening to appropriate the rents
Inability to prevent this may cause parties to inefficiently avoid making agreements!
Alfred Marshall
1842-1924
“Indeed, in some cases and for some purposes, nearly the whole income of a business may be regarded as a quasi-rent, that is an income determined for the time by the state of the market for its wares, with but little reference to the cost of preparing for their work the various things and persons engaged in it. In other words it is a composite quasi-rent divisible among the different persons in the business by bargaining, supplemented by custom and by notions of fairness...Thus the head clerk in a business has an acquaintance with men and things, the use of which he could in some cases sell at a high price to rival firms. But in other cases it is of a kind to be of no value save to the business in which he already is; and then his departure would perhaps injure it by several times the value of his salary, while probably he could not get half that salary elsewhere,” (VI.viii.35).
Benjamin Klein
1943-
“Coase's fundamental insight [was] that transaction, coordination, and contracting costs must be considered explicitly in explaining the extent of vertical integration...[We] explore one particular cost of using the market system-the possibility of postcontractual opportunistic behavior,” (p.297)
“The particular circumstance we emphasize as likely to produce a serious threat of this type of reneging on contracts is the presence of appropriable specialized quasi rents. After a specific investment is made and such quasi rents are created, the possibility of opportunistic behavior is very real. Following Coase's framework, this problem can be solved in two possible ways: vertical integration or contracts,” (p.298)
Benjamin Klein
1943-
“An appropriable quasi rent is not a monopoly rent in the usual sense, that is, the increased value of an asset protected from market entry over the value it would have in an open market. [It] can occur with no market closure or restrictions placed on rival assets. Once install, an asset may be so expensive to remove or so specialized to a particular user that if the price paid to the owner was somehow reduced the asset's services to that user would not be reduced,” (p.299).
Benjamin Klein
1943-
“Because of transaction and mobility costs, ‘market power’ will exist in many situations not commonly called monopolies. There may be many potential suppliers of a particular asset to a particular user but once the investment in the asset is made, the asset may be so specialized to a particular user that monopoly or monopsony power, or both, is created,” (p.299).
Klein, Benjamin, Robert G Crawford, and Armen A Alchian, 1978, "Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process," Journal of Law and Economics 21(2): 297-326
“Asset specificity”: degree to which an asset has alternative valuable uses outside a specific use
General assets can easily be diverted to other productive uses for most or all of their value
Olvier E Williamson
1932-
Economics Nobel 2009
“Four types of asset specificity are usefully distinguished:
[1.] site specificity - e.g. successive stations that are located in a cheek-by-jowl relation to each other so as to economize on inventory and transportation expenses;
[2.] physical asset specificity - e.g. specialized dies that are required to produce a component;
[3.] human asset specificity that arises in a learning-by-doing fashion; and
[4.] dedicated assets, which represent a discrete investment in generalized...production capacity that would not be made but for the prospect of selling a significant amount of product to a specific consumer,” (p. 95).
Olvier E Williamson
1932-
Economics Nobel 2009
“Transaction cost economics maintains that the principal factor that is responsible for transaction cost differences among transactions is variations in asset specificity. Transactions that are supported by non-specific (redeployable) investments are ones for which neoclassical analysis is well-suited to deal. As a condition of asset specificity becomes more important, however, exchange relations take on a progressively stronger bilateral trading character. The reason is that parties to such trades have a stake in preserving the continuity of the relationship,” (p. 367).
Riordan, Michael H and Oliver E Williamson, 1985, “Asset Specificity and Economic Organization,” International Journal of Industrial Organization 3: 365-378.
Based on Riordan and Williamson, 1985
\(\color{red}{\Delta G}\): difference in governance cost of organization (firm) vs. market
\(\color{blue}{\Delta C}\): difference in production costs of organization (firm) vs. market
Based on Riordan and Williamson, 1985
\(\color{red}{\Delta G}\): difference in governance cost of organization (firm) vs. market
\(\color{blue}{\Delta C}\): difference in production costs of organization (firm) vs. market
Based on Riordan and Williamson, 1985
At low levels of asset specificity \((k < k_2)\), market transactions are lower cost than organization
At higher levels of asset specificity \((k > k_2)\), organization is lower cost than market
At modest levels of asset specificity \(k_2\), no clear superior mode, may be a combination
Based on Riordan and Williamson, 1985
Suppose one party owns a generic asset - trucks
Another party owns a highly specific asset - highly specialized machines
Suppose a contract between them creates $50,000 of joint net value for the owner of the generic asset and the owner of the specific asset
Can't recontract until next year
Once the contract is signed, the owner of the generic asset threatens to pull out of the contract
Foreseeing such contractual hazards parties will be reluctant to cooperate
Or will choose a less specialized and less efficient technology
Two players, Party A and Party B
Party A incurs a sunk cost -C once contract is signed $$\color{red}{C>0.10\pi}$$
\(\big\{\)(Generic Tech, Give In), (Hold Up) \(\big\}\)†
† Strategies for Party A chosen at (A.1, A.2) and Party B at (B.1)
Suppose before Party A makes their initial decision, Party B supplies a bond or a hostage to Party A
Hostage will be forfeited if Party B does not Fulfill their contract:
\(\alpha\): fraction of \(H\) that is valuable to Party A
If \(\alpha H>0.10\pi+C\), Party A will Not Give In to a Hold Up, and Party B will thus Fulfill
\(\big\{\)(Specialized Contract, Don't Give In), (Fulfill) \(\big\}\)†
† Strategies for Party A chosen at (A.1, A.2) and Party B at (B.1)
Williamson, Oliver E, 1983, "Credible Commitments: Using Hostages to Support Exchange," American Economic Review
Consider a simple model of two-stage production:
Assume each unit of final product (sold by retailer to consumers) requires 1 unit of input (sold by manufacturer to retailer)
Each stage is a separate market, which could be competitive or monopolistic
\(\color{red}{MC_R}\) for Retailer = price for Manufacturer’s output \((MC_R=p_M)\)
Retailer sets \(MR=MC\) at \(q_R\) and marks up \(p_R>MC_R\) to consumers
\(\color{red}{MC_R}\) for Retailer = price for Manufacturer’s output \((MC_R=p_M)\)
Retailer sets \(MR=MC\) at \(q_R\) and marks up \(p_R>MC_R\) to consumers
Retailer earns Profits
Generates Consumer surplus and DWL
Note that Retailer's MR curve is the demand curve for the Manufacturer
If Manufacturer were to raise/lower price, Retailer would buy \(q^R\) where \(MR_R=MC_R\)
Note that Retailer's MR curve is the demand curve for the Manufacturer
If Manufacturer were to raise/lower price, Retailer would buy \(q^R\) where \(MR_R=MC_R\)
Note that Retailer's MR curve is the demand curve for the Manufacturer
If Manufacturer were to raise/lower price, Retailer would buy \(q^R\) where \(MR_R=MC_R\)
Describes \(q_R\) for every possible \(P_M\)!
So what price \(P^M\) will the Manufacturer set??
Since Manufacturer's \(\color{purple}{MR_M}\) curve is Retailer's Demand curve, consider Retailer's \(\color{darkblue}{MR_R}\) curve
It will set its own \(\color{darkred}{MC_M}=\color{darkblue}{MR_M}\)
Then markup the price to \(p_M\) (most Retailer is willing to pay!)
Since Manufacturer's \(\color{purple}{MR_M}\) curve is Retailer's Demand curve, consider Retailer's \(\color{darkblue}{MR_R}\) curve
It will set its own \(\color{darkred}{MC_M}=\color{darkblue}{MR_M}\)
Then markup the price to \(p_M\) (most Retailer is willing to pay!)
\(p_M\) becomes the new \(MC_R\) for Retailer
Retailer takes this higher \(\color{reD}{p_M=MC_R}\) and sets it equal to its own \(\color{purple}{MR_R}\)
Marks up the price to \(p_R\)
Manufacturer earns some profit
Retailer extracts some of this profit (darker)
Less Consumer Surplus
Much greater DWL from double markup
With bilateral monopoly, a double-markup causing:
Much less consumer surplus
Much more DWL
Less total profit (and it's split between Manufacturer & Retailer)
One solution to this problem is vertical integration: the firm internalizes a stage of production in the supply chain
Avoids hold up problems and post-contractual opportunism
Benjamin Klein
1943-
“[A]s assets become more specific and more appropriable quasi rents are created (and therefore the gains from opportunistic behavior increases), the costs of contracting will generally increase more than the costs of vertical integration. Hence, ceterus paribus, we are more likely to observe vertical integration,” (p.298).
Benjamin Klein
1943-
“We maintain that if an asset has a substantial portion of quasi rent which is strongly dependent upon some other particular asset, both assets will tend to be owned by one party,” (p.300).
Klein, Benjamin, Robert G Crawford, and Armen A Alchian, 1978, "Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process," Journal of Law and Economics 21(2): 297-326
Benjamin Klein
1943-
“The primary alternative to vertical integration as a solution to the general problem of opportunistic behavior is some form of economically enforceable long-term contract,” (p. 302).
Benjamin Klein
1943-
“Long-term contracts used as alternatives to vertical integration can be assumed to take two forms: (1) an explicitly stated contractual guarantee legally enforced by the government or some other outside institution, or (2) an implicit contractual guarantee enforced by the market mechanism of withdrawing future business if opportunistic behavior occurs...[However, they are] often very costly solutions. They entail costs of specifying possible contingencies and the policing and litigation costs of detecting violations and enforcing the contract in the courts..every contingency cannot be cheaply specified in a contract or even known and because legal redress is expensive...” (p.303).
Benjamin Klein
1943-
“The manufacture of dies for stamping parts in accordance with the above specifications [for a Mustang or Ford model] gives a value to these dies specialized to Ford, which implies an appropriable quasi rent in those dies...once the large sunk fixed cost of the specific investment in the dies is made, the incentive for Ford to opportunistically renegotiate a lower price at which it will accept body parts from the independent die owner may be large. Similarly, if there is a large cost to Ford from the production delay of obtaining an alternative supplier of the specific body parts, the independent die owner may be able to capture quasi rents by demanding a revised higher price for the parts. Since the opportunity to lose the specialized quasi rent of assets is a debilitating prospect, neither party would invest in such equipment. Joint ownership of designs and dies removes this incentive to attempt appropriation,” (p.308).
Benjamin Klein
1943-
“[I]n 1919 General Motors entered a ten-year contractual agreement with Fisher Body for the supply of closed auto bodies. In order to encourage Fisher Body to make the required specific investment, this contract had an exclusive dealing clause whereby General Motors agreed to buy substantially all its closed bodies from Fisher. This exclusive dealing arrangement significantly reduced the possibility of General Motors acting opportunistically by demanding a lower price for the bodies after Fisher made the specific investment in production capacity,”
Benjamin Klein
1943-
“But large opportunities were created by this exclusive dealing clause for Fisher to take advantage of General Motors, namely to demand a monopoly price for the bodies. Therefore, the contract attempted to fix the price which Fisher could charge for the bodies supplied to General Motors...The price was set on a cost plus 17.6 per cent basis [and had other provisions to protect GM].”
Benjamin Klein
1943-
“Unfortunately, however, these complex contractual pricing provisions did not work out in practice. The demand conditions facing General Motors and Fisher Body changed dramatically over the next few years. There was a large increase in the demand for automobiles and a significant shift away from open bodies to the closed body styles supplied by Fisher. Meanwhile, General Motors was very unhappy with the price it was being charged by its now very important supplier, Fisher...By 1924, General Motors had found the Fisher contractual relationship intolerable and began negotiations for purchase of the remaining stock in Fisher Body, culminating in a final merger agreement in 1926,” (pp.309-310).
Klein, Benjamin, Robert G Crawford, and Armen A Alchian, 1978, "Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process," Journal of Law and Economics 21(2): 297-326
Keyboard shortcuts
↑, ←, Pg Up, k | Go to previous slide |
↓, →, Pg Dn, Space, j | Go to next slide |
Home | Go to first slide |
End | Go to last slide |
Number + Return | Go to specific slide |
b / m / f | Toggle blackout / mirrored / fullscreen mode |
c | Clone slideshow |
p | Toggle presenter mode |
t | Restart the presentation timer |
?, h | Toggle this help |
o | Tile View: Overview of Slides |
Esc | Back to slideshow |
Ronald H. Coase
(1910-2013)
Economics Nobel 1991
John R. Commons
1862-1945
“[T]he ultimate unit of activity ... must contain in itself the three principles of conflict, mutuality, and order. This unit is a transaction,” (p.4).
Olvier E Williamson
1932-
Economics Nobel 2009
“As the term suggests, transaction cost economics adopts a microanalytic approach to the study of economic organization. The focus is on transactions and the economizing efforts that attend the organization thereof...With a well-working interface, as with a well-working machine, these transfers occur smoothly. In mechanical systems we look for frictions: Do the gears mesh, are the parts lubricated, is there needless slippage or other loss of energy?” (p.1).
Olvier E Williamson
1932-
Economics Nobel 2009
“The economic counterpart of friction is transaction cost: Do the parties to the exchange operate harmoniously, or are there frequent misunderstandings and conflicts that lead to delays, breakdowns, and other malfunctions? Transaction cost analysis supplants the usual preoccupation with technology and steady-state production (or distribution) expenses with an examination of the comparative costs of planning, adapting, and monitoring task completion under alternative governance structures.“ (pp.1-2).
Olvier E Williamson
1932-
Economics Nobel 2009
“Rather than characterize the firm as a production function, transaction cost economics maintains that the firm is (for many purposes at least) more usefully regarded as a governance structure.” (p.13)
“Contrary to earlier conceptions–where the economic institutions of capitalism are explained by reference to class interests, technology, and/or monopoly power–the transactions cost approach maintains that these institutions have the main purpose and effect of economizing on transaction costs,” (p.1).
Olvier E Williamson
1932-
Economics Nobel 2009
“Governance...is the means by which to infuse order, thereby to mitigate conflict and realize mutual gain...Furthermore, the transaction is made the basic unit of analysis,” (p.2).
Olvier E Williamson
1932-
Economics Nobel 2009
A contract between two parties constitutes a “fundamental transformation” from ex ante competitive market to an ex post bilateral monopoly
Creates the possibility of post-contractual opportunism by the parties
This bilateral dependency creates “quasi rents” from cooperation that might be appropriated by a party
Need to contract ex ante to protect ex post possibility of someone threatening to appropriate the rents
Inability to prevent this may cause parties to inefficiently avoid making agreements!
Alfred Marshall
1842-1924
“Indeed, in some cases and for some purposes, nearly the whole income of a business may be regarded as a quasi-rent, that is an income determined for the time by the state of the market for its wares, with but little reference to the cost of preparing for their work the various things and persons engaged in it. In other words it is a composite quasi-rent divisible among the different persons in the business by bargaining, supplemented by custom and by notions of fairness...Thus the head clerk in a business has an acquaintance with men and things, the use of which he could in some cases sell at a high price to rival firms. But in other cases it is of a kind to be of no value save to the business in which he already is; and then his departure would perhaps injure it by several times the value of his salary, while probably he could not get half that salary elsewhere,” (VI.viii.35).
Benjamin Klein
1943-
“Coase's fundamental insight [was] that transaction, coordination, and contracting costs must be considered explicitly in explaining the extent of vertical integration...[We] explore one particular cost of using the market system-the possibility of postcontractual opportunistic behavior,” (p.297)
“The particular circumstance we emphasize as likely to produce a serious threat of this type of reneging on contracts is the presence of appropriable specialized quasi rents. After a specific investment is made and such quasi rents are created, the possibility of opportunistic behavior is very real. Following Coase's framework, this problem can be solved in two possible ways: vertical integration or contracts,” (p.298)
Benjamin Klein
1943-
“An appropriable quasi rent is not a monopoly rent in the usual sense, that is, the increased value of an asset protected from market entry over the value it would have in an open market. [It] can occur with no market closure or restrictions placed on rival assets. Once install, an asset may be so expensive to remove or so specialized to a particular user that if the price paid to the owner was somehow reduced the asset's services to that user would not be reduced,” (p.299).
Benjamin Klein
1943-
“Because of transaction and mobility costs, ‘market power’ will exist in many situations not commonly called monopolies. There may be many potential suppliers of a particular asset to a particular user but once the investment in the asset is made, the asset may be so specialized to a particular user that monopoly or monopsony power, or both, is created,” (p.299).
Klein, Benjamin, Robert G Crawford, and Armen A Alchian, 1978, "Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process," Journal of Law and Economics 21(2): 297-326
“Asset specificity”: degree to which an asset has alternative valuable uses outside a specific use
General assets can easily be diverted to other productive uses for most or all of their value
Olvier E Williamson
1932-
Economics Nobel 2009
“Four types of asset specificity are usefully distinguished:
[1.] site specificity - e.g. successive stations that are located in a cheek-by-jowl relation to each other so as to economize on inventory and transportation expenses;
[2.] physical asset specificity - e.g. specialized dies that are required to produce a component;
[3.] human asset specificity that arises in a learning-by-doing fashion; and
[4.] dedicated assets, which represent a discrete investment in generalized...production capacity that would not be made but for the prospect of selling a significant amount of product to a specific consumer,” (p. 95).
Olvier E Williamson
1932-
Economics Nobel 2009
“Transaction cost economics maintains that the principal factor that is responsible for transaction cost differences among transactions is variations in asset specificity. Transactions that are supported by non-specific (redeployable) investments are ones for which neoclassical analysis is well-suited to deal. As a condition of asset specificity becomes more important, however, exchange relations take on a progressively stronger bilateral trading character. The reason is that parties to such trades have a stake in preserving the continuity of the relationship,” (p. 367).
Riordan, Michael H and Oliver E Williamson, 1985, “Asset Specificity and Economic Organization,” International Journal of Industrial Organization 3: 365-378.
Based on Riordan and Williamson, 1985
\(\color{red}{\Delta G}\): difference in governance cost of organization (firm) vs. market
\(\color{blue}{\Delta C}\): difference in production costs of organization (firm) vs. market
Based on Riordan and Williamson, 1985
\(\color{red}{\Delta G}\): difference in governance cost of organization (firm) vs. market
\(\color{blue}{\Delta C}\): difference in production costs of organization (firm) vs. market
Based on Riordan and Williamson, 1985
At low levels of asset specificity \((k < k_2)\), market transactions are lower cost than organization
At higher levels of asset specificity \((k > k_2)\), organization is lower cost than market
At modest levels of asset specificity \(k_2\), no clear superior mode, may be a combination
Based on Riordan and Williamson, 1985
Suppose one party owns a generic asset - trucks
Another party owns a highly specific asset - highly specialized machines
Suppose a contract between them creates $50,000 of joint net value for the owner of the generic asset and the owner of the specific asset
Can't recontract until next year
Once the contract is signed, the owner of the generic asset threatens to pull out of the contract
Foreseeing such contractual hazards parties will be reluctant to cooperate
Or will choose a less specialized and less efficient technology
Two players, Party A and Party B
Party A incurs a sunk cost -C once contract is signed $$\color{red}{C>0.10\pi}$$
\(\big\{\)(Generic Tech, Give In), (Hold Up) \(\big\}\)†
† Strategies for Party A chosen at (A.1, A.2) and Party B at (B.1)
Suppose before Party A makes their initial decision, Party B supplies a bond or a hostage to Party A
Hostage will be forfeited if Party B does not Fulfill their contract:
\(\alpha\): fraction of \(H\) that is valuable to Party A
If \(\alpha H>0.10\pi+C\), Party A will Not Give In to a Hold Up, and Party B will thus Fulfill
\(\big\{\)(Specialized Contract, Don't Give In), (Fulfill) \(\big\}\)†
† Strategies for Party A chosen at (A.1, A.2) and Party B at (B.1)
Williamson, Oliver E, 1983, "Credible Commitments: Using Hostages to Support Exchange," American Economic Review
Consider a simple model of two-stage production:
Assume each unit of final product (sold by retailer to consumers) requires 1 unit of input (sold by manufacturer to retailer)
Each stage is a separate market, which could be competitive or monopolistic
\(\color{red}{MC_R}\) for Retailer = price for Manufacturer’s output \((MC_R=p_M)\)
Retailer sets \(MR=MC\) at \(q_R\) and marks up \(p_R>MC_R\) to consumers
\(\color{red}{MC_R}\) for Retailer = price for Manufacturer’s output \((MC_R=p_M)\)
Retailer sets \(MR=MC\) at \(q_R\) and marks up \(p_R>MC_R\) to consumers
Retailer earns Profits
Generates Consumer surplus and DWL
Note that Retailer's MR curve is the demand curve for the Manufacturer
If Manufacturer were to raise/lower price, Retailer would buy \(q^R\) where \(MR_R=MC_R\)
Note that Retailer's MR curve is the demand curve for the Manufacturer
If Manufacturer were to raise/lower price, Retailer would buy \(q^R\) where \(MR_R=MC_R\)
Note that Retailer's MR curve is the demand curve for the Manufacturer
If Manufacturer were to raise/lower price, Retailer would buy \(q^R\) where \(MR_R=MC_R\)
Describes \(q_R\) for every possible \(P_M\)!
So what price \(P^M\) will the Manufacturer set??
Since Manufacturer's \(\color{purple}{MR_M}\) curve is Retailer's Demand curve, consider Retailer's \(\color{darkblue}{MR_R}\) curve
It will set its own \(\color{darkred}{MC_M}=\color{darkblue}{MR_M}\)
Then markup the price to \(p_M\) (most Retailer is willing to pay!)
Since Manufacturer's \(\color{purple}{MR_M}\) curve is Retailer's Demand curve, consider Retailer's \(\color{darkblue}{MR_R}\) curve
It will set its own \(\color{darkred}{MC_M}=\color{darkblue}{MR_M}\)
Then markup the price to \(p_M\) (most Retailer is willing to pay!)
\(p_M\) becomes the new \(MC_R\) for Retailer
Retailer takes this higher \(\color{reD}{p_M=MC_R}\) and sets it equal to its own \(\color{purple}{MR_R}\)
Marks up the price to \(p_R\)
Manufacturer earns some profit
Retailer extracts some of this profit (darker)
Less Consumer Surplus
Much greater DWL from double markup
With bilateral monopoly, a double-markup causing:
Much less consumer surplus
Much more DWL
Less total profit (and it's split between Manufacturer & Retailer)
One solution to this problem is vertical integration: the firm internalizes a stage of production in the supply chain
Avoids hold up problems and post-contractual opportunism
Benjamin Klein
1943-
“[A]s assets become more specific and more appropriable quasi rents are created (and therefore the gains from opportunistic behavior increases), the costs of contracting will generally increase more than the costs of vertical integration. Hence, ceterus paribus, we are more likely to observe vertical integration,” (p.298).
Benjamin Klein
1943-
“We maintain that if an asset has a substantial portion of quasi rent which is strongly dependent upon some other particular asset, both assets will tend to be owned by one party,” (p.300).
Klein, Benjamin, Robert G Crawford, and Armen A Alchian, 1978, "Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process," Journal of Law and Economics 21(2): 297-326
Benjamin Klein
1943-
“The primary alternative to vertical integration as a solution to the general problem of opportunistic behavior is some form of economically enforceable long-term contract,” (p. 302).
Benjamin Klein
1943-
“Long-term contracts used as alternatives to vertical integration can be assumed to take two forms: (1) an explicitly stated contractual guarantee legally enforced by the government or some other outside institution, or (2) an implicit contractual guarantee enforced by the market mechanism of withdrawing future business if opportunistic behavior occurs...[However, they are] often very costly solutions. They entail costs of specifying possible contingencies and the policing and litigation costs of detecting violations and enforcing the contract in the courts..every contingency cannot be cheaply specified in a contract or even known and because legal redress is expensive...” (p.303).
Benjamin Klein
1943-
“The manufacture of dies for stamping parts in accordance with the above specifications [for a Mustang or Ford model] gives a value to these dies specialized to Ford, which implies an appropriable quasi rent in those dies...once the large sunk fixed cost of the specific investment in the dies is made, the incentive for Ford to opportunistically renegotiate a lower price at which it will accept body parts from the independent die owner may be large. Similarly, if there is a large cost to Ford from the production delay of obtaining an alternative supplier of the specific body parts, the independent die owner may be able to capture quasi rents by demanding a revised higher price for the parts. Since the opportunity to lose the specialized quasi rent of assets is a debilitating prospect, neither party would invest in such equipment. Joint ownership of designs and dies removes this incentive to attempt appropriation,” (p.308).
Benjamin Klein
1943-
“[I]n 1919 General Motors entered a ten-year contractual agreement with Fisher Body for the supply of closed auto bodies. In order to encourage Fisher Body to make the required specific investment, this contract had an exclusive dealing clause whereby General Motors agreed to buy substantially all its closed bodies from Fisher. This exclusive dealing arrangement significantly reduced the possibility of General Motors acting opportunistically by demanding a lower price for the bodies after Fisher made the specific investment in production capacity,”
Benjamin Klein
1943-
“But large opportunities were created by this exclusive dealing clause for Fisher to take advantage of General Motors, namely to demand a monopoly price for the bodies. Therefore, the contract attempted to fix the price which Fisher could charge for the bodies supplied to General Motors...The price was set on a cost plus 17.6 per cent basis [and had other provisions to protect GM].”
Benjamin Klein
1943-
“Unfortunately, however, these complex contractual pricing provisions did not work out in practice. The demand conditions facing General Motors and Fisher Body changed dramatically over the next few years. There was a large increase in the demand for automobiles and a significant shift away from open bodies to the closed body styles supplied by Fisher. Meanwhile, General Motors was very unhappy with the price it was being charged by its now very important supplier, Fisher...By 1924, General Motors had found the Fisher contractual relationship intolerable and began negotiations for purchase of the remaining stock in Fisher Body, culminating in a final merger agreement in 1926,” (pp.309-310).
Klein, Benjamin, Robert G Crawford, and Armen A Alchian, 1978, "Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process," Journal of Law and Economics 21(2): 297-326